John Brockman - What Should We Be Worried About?

Здесь есть возможность читать онлайн «John Brockman - What Should We Be Worried About?» весь текст электронной книги совершенно бесплатно (целиком полную версию без сокращений). В некоторых случаях можно слушать аудио, скачать через торрент в формате fb2 и присутствует краткое содержание. Город: New York, Год выпуска: 2014, ISBN: 2014, Издательство: Harper Perennial, Жанр: Прочая научная литература, Публицистика, на английском языке. Описание произведения, (предисловие) а так же отзывы посетителей доступны на портале библиотеки ЛибКат.

What Should We Be Worried About?: краткое содержание, описание и аннотация

Предлагаем к чтению аннотацию, описание, краткое содержание или предисловие (зависит от того, что написал сам автор книги «What Should We Be Worried About?»). Если вы не нашли необходимую информацию о книге — напишите в комментариях, мы постараемся отыскать её.

Drawing from the horizons of science, today’s leading thinkers reveal the hidden threats nobody is talking about—and expose the false fears everyone else is distracted by.
What should we be worried about? That is the question John Brockman, publisher of Edge.org (“The world’s smartest website”—The Guardian), posed to the planet’s most influential minds. He asked them to disclose something that, for scientific reasons, worries them—particularly scenarios that aren’t on the popular radar yet. Encompassing neuroscience, economics, philosophy, physics, psychology, biology, and more—here are 150 ideas that will revolutionize your understanding of the world.
Steven Pinker uncovers the real risk factors for war • Mihaly Csikszentmihalyi peers into the coming virtual abyss • Nobel laureate Frank Wilczek laments our squandered opportunities to prevent global catastrophe • Seth Lloyd calculates the threat of a financial black hole • Alison Gopnik on the loss of childhood • Nassim Nicholas Taleb explains why firefighters understand risk far better than economic “experts” • Matt Ridley on the alarming re-emergence of superstition • Daniel C. Dennett and george dyson ponder the impact of a major breakdown of the Internet • Jennifer Jacquet fears human-induced damage to the planet due to “the Anthropocebo Effect” • Douglas Rushkoff fears humanity is losing its soul • Nicholas Carr on the “patience deficit” • Tim O’Reilly foresees a coming new Dark Age • Scott Atran on the homogenization of human experience • Sherry Turkle explores what’s lost when kids are constantly connected • Kevin Kelly outlines the looming “underpopulation bomb” • Helen Fisher on the fate of men • Lawrence Krauss dreads what we don’t know about the universe • Susan Blackmore on the loss of manual skills • Kate Jeffery on the death of death • plus J. Craig Venter, Daniel Goleman, Virginia Heffernan, Sam Harris, Brian Eno, Martin Rees, and more.

What Should We Be Worried About? — читать онлайн бесплатно полную книгу (весь текст) целиком

Ниже представлен текст книги, разбитый по страницам. Система сохранения места последней прочитанной страницы, позволяет с удобством читать онлайн бесплатно книгу «What Should We Be Worried About?», без необходимости каждый раз заново искать на чём Вы остановились. Поставьте закладку, и сможете в любой момент перейти на страницу, на которой закончили чтение.

Тёмная тема
Сбросить

Интервал:

Закладка:

Сделать

What exactly are we looking for, then?

We are looking for ways to let our imagination be free, to breathe new ideas, to think in a way not explained only by the logic and incentives of the mediasphere. How can this be done? Poetry is a kind of research that can help. Digital humanities are a path to enhance our ability to think differently. We need to develop an epistemology of information.

Knowledge is meant to set us free, provided that we preserve our ability to decide what is important, independent of what is defined as important by the platform we use. Freedom of expression is not only the quantity of different ideas that circulate (the wealth of which has never been as rich as it is today). Freedom of expression is also about the decision making that lets us choose ideas that are better than others, to improve our ability to live together.

We should be worried about how we go about finding the wisdom to allow us to navigate developments, as we begin to improve our ability to cheaply print human tissue, grow synthetic brains, have robots take care of our aging parents, let the Internet educate our children. Ungaretti would have thought, maybe, that what is required is only a digitally aware name for ethics, aesthetics, and poetry.

WHAT WE LEARN FROM FIREFIGHTERS: HOW FAT ARE THE FAT TAILS?

NASSIM NICHOLAS TALEB

Distinguished Professor of Risk Engineering, NYU Polytechnic Institute; author, Antifragile: Things That Gain from Disorder

Eight years ago, I showed, using 20 million pieces of data from socioeconomic variables (about all the data that was available at the time), that current tools in economics and econometrics don’t work whenever there is an exposure to a large set of deviations, or “Black Swans.” There was a gigantic mammoth in the middle of the classroom. Simply, one observation in 10,000—that is, one day in forty years—can explain the bulk of the “kurtosis,” a measure of what we call “fat tails,” that is, how much the distribution under consideration departs from the standard Gaussian, or the role of remote events in determining the total properties. For the U.S. stock market, a single day, the crash of 1987, determined 80 percent of the kurtosis. The same problem is found with interest and exchange rates, commodities, and other variables. The problem is not just that the data had “fat tails”—something people knew but sort of wanted to forget; it was that we would never be able to determine how “fat” the tails were. Never.

The implication is that those tools used in economics that are based on squaring variables (more technically, the Euclidian, or L-2 norm), such as standard deviation, variance, correlation, regression, or value-at-risk—the kind of stuff you find in textbooks—are not valid scientifically (except in some rare cases where the variable is bounded). The so-called “p values” you find in studies have no meaning with economic and financial variables. Even the more sophisticated techniques of stochastic calculus used in mathematical finance do not work in economics except in selected pockets.

The results of most papers in economics based on these standard statistical methods—the kind of stuff people learn in statistics class—are thus not expected to replicate, and they effectively don’t. Further, these tools invite foolish risk-taking. Neither do alternative techniques yield reliable measures of rare events, except that we can tell if a remote event is underpriced, without assigning an exact value.

The Evidence

The story took a depressing turn, as follows: I put together this evidence—in addition to a-priori mathematical derivations showing the impossibility of some statistical claims—as a companion for The Black Swan . The papers sat for years on the Web, were posted on Edge (ironically the Edge posting took place only a few hours before the announcement of the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers). They were downloaded tens of thousands of times on SSRN (the Social Science Research Network). For good measure, a technical version was published in a peer-reviewed statistical journal.

I thought that the story had ended there and that people would pay attention to the evidence; after all, I played by the exact rules of scientific revelation, communication, and transmission of evidence. Nothing happened. To make things worse, I sold millions of copies of The Black Swan and nothing happened, so it cannot be that the results were not properly disseminated. I even testified in front of a congressional committee (twice). There was even a model-caused financial crisis, for Baal’s sake, and nothing happened. The only counters I received were that I was “repetitive,” “egocentric,” “arrogant,” “angry,” or something even more insubstantial, meant to demonize the messenger. Nobody has managed to explain why it is not charlatanism, downright scientifically fraudulent, to use these techniques.

Absence of Skin in the Game

It all became clear when, one day, I received the following message from a firefighter. His point was that he found my ideas on tail risk extremely easy to understand. His question was: How come risk gurus, academics, and financial modelers don’t get it?

Well, the answer was right there, staring at me, in the message itself. The fellow, as a firefighter, could not afford to misunderstand risk and statistical properties. He would be directly harmed by his error. In other words, he has skin in the game. And, in addition, he is honorable, risking his life for others, not making others take risks for his sake.

So the root cause of this model fraud has to be absence of skin in the game, combined with too much money and power at stake. Had the modelers and predictors been harmed by their own mistakes, they would have exited the gene pool—or raised their level of morality. Someone else (society) pays the price of the mistakes. Clearly, the academic profession consists in playing a game, pleasing the editors of “prestigious” journals, or being “highly cited.” When confronted, they offer the nihilistic fallacy that “We’ve got to start somewhere”—which could justify using astrology as a basis for science. And the business is unbelievably circular: A “successful PhD program” is one that has “good results” in the “job market” for academic positions. I was told bluntly at a certain business school where I refused to teach risk models and “modern portfolio theory” that my mission as a professor was to help students get jobs. I find all of this highly immoral—immoral to create harm for profit. Primum non nocere .

Only a rule of skin in the game—that is, direct harm from one’s errors—can puncture the game aspect of such research and establish some form of contact with reality.

LAMPLIGHT PROBABILITIES

BART KOSKO

Information scientist & professor of electrical engineering & law, University of Southern California; author, Noise

We should worry that much of our science and technology still uses just five main models of probability, even though there are more probability models than there are real numbers. I call these lamplight probabilities. The adjective refers to the old joke about the drunk who lost his keys somewhere in the dark and looks for them under the streetlamp because that’s where the light is.

The five lamplight probabilities do explain a lot of the observed world. They have simple closed-form definitions. So they are easy to teach. Open any book on probability and there they are. We have proved lots of theorems about them. And they generalize to many other simple closed-form probabilities that also seem to explain a lot of the world and find their way into real-world models ranging from finance to communications to nuclear engineering.

Читать дальше
Тёмная тема
Сбросить

Интервал:

Закладка:

Сделать

Похожие книги на «What Should We Be Worried About?»

Представляем Вашему вниманию похожие книги на «What Should We Be Worried About?» списком для выбора. Мы отобрали схожую по названию и смыслу литературу в надежде предоставить читателям больше вариантов отыскать новые, интересные, ещё непрочитанные произведения.


Отзывы о книге «What Should We Be Worried About?»

Обсуждение, отзывы о книге «What Should We Be Worried About?» и просто собственные мнения читателей. Оставьте ваши комментарии, напишите, что Вы думаете о произведении, его смысле или главных героях. Укажите что конкретно понравилось, а что нет, и почему Вы так считаете.

x